Our address:

Ed Newbold
#1 Economy Arcade, 93 Pike Street, Seattle, Washington 98101

Pike Place Market Website:

Pike Place Market

Call the store:

(206) 652 5215

The ‘Amazon’ head tax: bad! ‘Amazon’ drone delivery tax: Good! –Here’s why (And I’ll explain the sheep)
12749
post-template-default,single,single-post,postid-12749,single-format-standard,theme-bridge,bridge-core-3.1.6,woocommerce-no-js,qode-page-transition-enabled,ajax_updown_fade,page_not_loaded,boxed,,side_area_uncovered_from_content,overlapping_content,columns-4,qode-child-theme-ver-1.0.0,qode-theme-ver-30.4.2,qode-theme-bridge,wpb-js-composer js-comp-ver-7.6,vc_responsive,elementor-default,elementor-kit-12768

The ‘Amazon’ head tax: bad! ‘Amazon’ drone delivery tax: Good! –Here’s why (And I’ll explain the sheep)

The ‘Amazon’ head tax: bad! ‘Amazon’ drone delivery tax: Good! –Here’s why (And I’ll explain the sheep)

Posted from Seattle, WA on Earth Day, April 22, 2020.

The head tax is a bad idea.  It runs up against a law of microeconomics, that cannot be rescinded by elected officials.  That is the law of the downward-sloping-demand-curve that says that if you tax something, you will get less of it.  If widgets are selling for $10 and a $2 tax is placed on widgets, fewer widgets will sold, all other factors being equal.

A Caspian Tern flying over Elliott Bay with the City of Seattle in the background painting by Ed Newbold

The law does not say how many fewer jobs we will have if we tax jobs, and therein lies room for reasonable disputations. Theoretically the number of jobs lost as a result of the new tax could be tiny with almost no lower limit, more on that later. What is certain is that the tax will exert a downward pressure on job creation in Seattle. But there is another problem with this particular tax:

What is the cost of avoiding this tax?

Taxes always create some degree of tax-avoidance behavior. In Washington state we tax cigarettes, and consumers as a result have been eager to cross juridictional boundaries to buy cigarettes from the nearest store the tax is not charged. With tax avoidance behavior, the key question for the efficiency of the tax mechanism is, how much of a monopoly does the taxing district possess? In some tax situations, there is nothing like a monopoly. If in Seattle we toll 1st Ave and not 2nd Ave, a great number of motorists will switch from 1st to 2nd, which involves very little cost. So it would not be advisable to toll 1st Ave only. With the national inheritance tax, avoidance is difficult but the stakes are high and so a high cost of avoidance can seem very worth paying to a prospective tax payer.. Commentators including inheritance-tax proponents often point to the modest amount that is collected by this tax as a reason for thinking the inheritance tax is not such a big deal. But an industry has grown up for tax accountants and lawyers who help people avoid this tax. The tax therefor drives a lot of economic activity thatis not in any way productive, either for taxpayers or for the Government. A reasonable question to ask about any tax is how possible is tax-avoidance behavior , how much inefficiency will this behavior create, and how much will it decrease projected revenue from the tax. In the case of a Seattle Head Tax, avodance can be extremely low-cost and easy. A business planning to hire in Seattle can easily rent an office in Bellevue, Renton or Lynnwood instead. This bodes ill for efficiency. It does not mean Seattle will die of job-strangulation but it should be considered a possible warning sign.

How many fewer jobs? 

How many fewer jobs will be created as a result of the law is determined by the elasticity of demand for creating jobs in the place where the head-tax is levied. There have been warnings from the tax opponents that this will kill Seattle.  If people are consumed by a desire to have their offices and job sites in Seattle because of past investments there or because Seattle is just so immensely cool, that will mean the demand is inelastic and there won’t be a lot of jobs lost, perhaps only a tiny number..  If investors love Seattle but are also drawn in by the allure of Spokane, Boise or Chicago, Lynnwood or Renton, the desire to invest in job creation in Seattle might be quite amazingly elastic.  A jobs tax could take us from job-health to job crisis in a hurry, under the highly elastic scenario. 

It’s not worth finding out how elastic the market is.  The City Council should vote the head tax down, and since it hits companies like the Seattle Times and Kaiser Permanente, they should quit calling it the Amazon tax, a big misrepresentation (thanks Danny Westneat Seattle Times April 13, 2020).

A Head Tax could turn the lights out in Seattle painting by Ed Newbold

But let’s not miss the clue…

But the downward-sloping demand law should point using another direction entirely. How about taxing externalities, i.e., “bad things,” rather than good things. After all, “when we tax something, we get less of i.,” GreenReboot dislikes all the regressive taxes that tax things that are essentially good, like property taxes which fall hardest on the poor, sales taxes which fall hardest on the poor, and payroll taxes which fall hardest on the poor. It makes sense to do a TAX SHIFT away from this “taxation of good things”  to taxation of a ‘taxation of bad things. In market terminology, bad things are called ‘externalities’—costs imposed on people but not paid for by the imposer–and money raised from rents on the use of government-owned assets, which usually also are associated with externalities.

Drone Delivery will bring external costs that will be borne by all of us

I have been very disappointed that people are accepting the onrush of drone delivery as a fait accompli. An headline in the Seattle Times on September 1, 2020 says “FAA clears Amazon to begin testing deliveries by drone.” It is very sheep-like of people to do this. We have a right to debate these things and decide we do or don’t want it, and we can also throw a tax on drone delivery. A very high tax would make drone delivery less bothersome but it might inspire a black market and this is a bad time to try to call the cops about something mundane. tax on Drone Delivery –which is coming like a fast freight on a railroad track–could eventually raise serious money and best of all would reduce Drone Delivery

People are being astonishingty sheeplike in their passive acceptance of drone delivery in their neighborhoods. Absolutely nothing has been proposed that would compensate people for the added noise, irritation and wildlife-loss that this will create.

Think about what drone delivery could mean for your neighborhood and your ability to pursue happiness.  Any time you are outside near the street, machines with whirling sharp metal blades that make a whiney, annoying, creepy sound will be added to your experience of life. This machine could injure or kill you if anything goes wrong. (a recreational drone has already killed its operator in at least one case.) Of course Drone Delivery would have an up-side. A drone could deliver medication quickly to a stroke or snake-bite victim. But that would be rare and exempt from our tax. Let’s face it, Drones will mostly be bringing pizza and ice cream to people who have enough money to not need to plan their ice-cream buying. Under the stiff new tax, people could order up drone delivery, but they would have to think hard about it, so there wouldn’t be a zillion drones flying through everyone’s neighborhood, and government would get a steady stream of reliable income. Tax avoidance behavior would decrease government revenue, but it would simultaneously make all of our lives better and not decrease societal or economic efficiency.

Drone Delivery: Exactly what we SHOULD be taxing

It makes sense to tax goods that use public rights of way. It makes sense to tax goods that have externalities–that is, they impose costs on others besides their paying customers. If a drone buxxes down your street, you are forced to listen, if you are interested in your own security you will have to keep track that it isn’t going off track, and you will have to look at it, and take it from a professional artist, drones can be ugly. They are a perfect example of a good that imposes an external cost. These are the things we should tax–things people don’t really need and that annoy and inconvenience others and degenerate the quality of other people’s lives.

A Violet-green Swallow dad feeding his chick. Photo by Ed Newbold

People will look back on the Generation that traded Swallows in the sky for Drones in the sky

Swallows used to be abundant in the city of Seattle.  Barn Swallows and Violet-green Swallows winged over the neighborhoods and Purple Martins nested in the downtown.  If you were walking on Capitol Hill on a summer day in 1970, you could look up and usually see a Swallow in graceful flight foraging for insects.  These Swallows are now struggling to keep a toehold in a city where they were once welcome. Only occasionally in the summer does a Seattleite now look up and see a Swallow.  By the end of the 20’s in a quite likely evil scenario, a Seattleite could look up and never see a Swallow but always see a drone.  In order to not complete this trade—Swallows for drones—we’ll have to do something to help Swallows and something to hold drone use at a low enough level that drones remain rare, …And the space where drones are not is space we can invite our Swallows to return to.

Let’s do it.

No Comments

Sorry, the comment form is closed at this time.